B. A. Albassam, Economic diversification in Saudi Arabia: Myth or reality?, Resources Policy, vol.44, pp.112-117, 2015.

A. Al-hawwas, Policy experiments for the Saudi's economy using a Computable General Equilibrium Model (CGE), oil demand and tariff liberalization effects on the Saudi economy, 2010.

J. Allegret, C. Couharde, V. Mignon, and T. Razafindrabe, Oil currencies in the face of oil shocks: what can be learned from timevarying specifications?, Applied Economics, vol.49, issue.18, pp.1774-1793, 2016.
URL : https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01411817

I. A. Al-thumairi, Fixed or flexible exchange rate for Saudi Arabia: optimal solution of CGE model, International Journal of Basic and Applied Sciences, vol.1, issue.2, pp.67-87, 2012.

Y. Alyousef and M. Abu-ebid, Energy efficiency initiatives for Saudi Arabia on supply and demand sides". In Energy Efficiency-A Bridge to Low Carbon Economy, 2012.

Y. Alyousef and P. Stevens, The cost of domestic energy prices to Saudi Arabia, Energy Policy, vol.39, issue.11, pp.6900-6905, 2011.

Y. Alyousef and A. Varnham, Saudi Arabia's National Energy Efficiency Programme: description, achievements and way forward, International Journal of Low-Carbon Technologies, vol.5, 2010.

, Saudi energy price reform getting serious, Arab Petroleum Investments Corporation, vol.03, 2018.

J. Barnett, S. Dessai, and M. Webber, Will OPEC lose from the Kyoto Protocol?, Energy Policy, vol.32, issue.18, pp.183-189, 2004.

N. Bauer, I. Mouratiadou, G. Luderer, L. Baumstark, R. J. Brecha et al., Global Fossil Energy Markets and Climate Change Mitigation: An Analysis with REMIND, Climatic Change, vol.136, issue.1, pp.69-82, 2013.

R. Bems and I. De-carvalho-filho, The current account and precautionary savings for exporters of exhaustible resources, Journal of International Economics, vol.84, issue.1, pp.48-64, 2011.

D. G. Blanchflower and A. J. Oswald, The wage curve reloaded, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2005.

J. Blazquez, L. Hunt, and B. Manzano, Oil subsidies and renewable energy in Saudi Arabia: A general equilibrium approach, The Energy Journal, vol.38, issue.S11, pp.29-45, 2017.

V. Brémond, E. Hache, and V. Mignon, Does OPEC still exist as a cartel? An empirical investigation, Energy Economics, vol.34, issue.1, pp.125-131, 2012.

,

R. D. Cairns and E. Calfucura, OPEC: Market failure or power failure, Energy Policy, vol.50, pp.570-580, 2012.

. Cdsi, Central Department of Statistics and Information, 2014.

A. H. , The Kingdom of Saudi Arabia, 2014.

M. A. Chemingui and H. Lofgren, Tax policy reform in Saudi Arabia: A general equilibrium analysis, Communication at The ERF 11th Annual Conference, 2004.

, POLICY_REFORM_IN_SAUDI_ARABIA_A_GENERAL_EQUILIBRIUM_ANALYSIS/links/54ef97460 cf2432ba656e72c.pdf

J. D. Colgan, The emperor has no clothes: The limits of OPEC in the global oil market, International Organization, vol.68, issue.3, pp.599-632, 2014.

E. Combet, F. Ghersi, J. Lefevre, and G. Le-treut, Construction of hybrid Input-Output tables for E3 CGE model calibration and consequences on energy policy analysis, GTAP Resource, vol.4524, 2014.
URL : https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01697841

H. Dai, P. Mischke, X. Xie, Y. Xie, and T. Masui, Closing the gap? Top-down versus bottom-up projections of China's regional energy use and CO2 emissions, Applied Energy, vol.162, pp.1355-1373, 2016.

, Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries, 2017.

S. Robinson, Multisectoral models". Handbook of development economics, vol.2, pp.885-947, 1989.

, Saudi Arabian Monetary Authority : Annual Statistics, 2017.

A. Schäfer and H. D. Jacoby, Experiments with a hybrid CGE-MARKAL model, The Energy Journal, pp.171-177, 2006.

A. Sen, Neo-classical and Neo-Keynesian theories of distribution, Economic Record, vol.39, pp.53-64, 1963.

R. M. Solow, Toward a macroeconomics of the medium run, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol.14, issue.1, pp.151-158, 2000.

T. Van-de-graaf and A. Verbruggen, The oil endgame: Strategies of oil exporters in a carbon-constrained world, Environmental Science & Policy, vol.54, pp.456-562, 2015.

E. Van-der-werf, Production functions for climate policy modeling: An empirical analysis, Energy Economics, vol.30, issue.6, pp.2964-2979, 2008.

H. Waisman, J. Rozenberg, and J. Hourcade, Monetary compensations in climate policy through the lens of a general equilibrium assessment: The case of oil-exporting countries, Energy Policy, vol.63, pp.951-961, 2013.
URL : https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-00944608

, OPEC has never constituted a cartel. In light of such evidence, we assume exogenous oil price trajectories in all our scenarios

, Given that oil demand is projected to increase in both scenarios (global oil demand in the SDS peaks in the mid-2020), current under-investment in oil resources is projected to raise oil prices up to 2025. 39 Beyond this horizon, outlooks diverge: moderate climate policy will sustain oil demand, driving oil price up in the NPS. In contrast, higher penetration of electric vehicles and larger efficiency gains in the transport sector in addition to climate policy tightening will cause the oil price to decline under the SDS, Our oil price scenarios derive from IEA, 2017.

, Saudi Arabia exported around 7 mb/d crude oil, 41 whereas refined products exports, By, 2017.

, For the remaining sectors, i.e. crude oil and refined products, we assume that (1) the Saudi output of crude oil reaches 12.7 mb/d by 2030. This corresponds to the Saudi oil supply projected by the IEA (2017) in the NPS. This requires additional output of around 2 mb/d compared to current levels. However, according to existing estimates, Saudi Arabia already has a spare capacity, our Baseline scenario, KEM reports natural gas output and electricity generation based on energy prices as previously described, 2017.

, ) Imports of refined products, which in fact correspond to total Saudi energy imports, follow potential growth at 2.23% per year up to, vol.42

, KEM provides natural gas output and electricity generation based on reformed tariffs. We maintain the assumption that both supplies meet domestic demand only. Concerning oil, we assume that Saudi Arabia keeps its export volume unchanged 41 This resulted from an output cut following OPEC and non-OPEC accord

, In our Reformed scenario, the penetration of renewables and nuclear increases the capital cost of power generation, than alternative technologies

, The resulting aggregate capital intensity of energy production remains broadly stable in the

, Baseline (and hence Low-oil-price) scenario, although ending some 2.5% below its 2013 level in 2030 thanks to increased utilisation rates-output increases faster than capital expenditures relative to the base year (+45.6% vs. +25.1%)